Ground Rent
Capital Volume 3, Part 6,
Transformation of Surplus-Profit into Ground-Rent
In this 11-chapter part of Capital Volume 3, Karl Marx
relates capital (reproduction of surplus value) to the much older,
pre-capitalist concept and practice of rent. He shows how rent became, and
remains, part of the capitalistic system.
Our chosen Chapter 38
(download linked below) deals with the “surplus-profit” over and above the
general rate of profit, that may arise from fortuitous factors like the
possession of a waterfall; and the concept of differential rent as a means of
taking account of such a variation from the norm.
But first, let us exploit the summarising paragraphs on
rent, given below in a shortened version, which Marx gives in the Introduction
to this section. Note that, as Marx reminds us, these remarks bear upon the
question of mining as much as they bear
upon agriculture:
“The analysis of
landed property in its various historical forms is beyond the scope of this
work. We shall be concerned with it only
in so far as a portion of the surplus-value produced by capital falls to the
share of the landowner. We assume, then, that agriculture is dominated by
the capitalist mode of production just as manufacture is; in other words, that
agriculture is carried on by capitalists who differ from other capitalists
primarily in the manner in which their capital, and the wage-labour set in
motion by this capital, are invested. So far as we are concerned, the farmer
produces wheat, etc., in much the same way as the manufacturer produces yarn or
machines. The assumption that the capitalist mode of production has encompassed
agriculture implies that it rules over all spheres of production and bourgeois
society, i.e., that its prerequisites, such as free competition among capitals,
the possibility of transferring the latter from one production sphere to
another, and a uniform level of the average profit, etc., are fully matured.
The form of landed property which we shall consider here is a specifically
historical one, a form transformed through the influence of capital and of the
capitalist mode of production, either of feudal landownership, or of
small-peasant agriculture as a means of livelihood, in which the possession of
the land and the soil constitutes one of the prerequisites of production for
the direct producer, and in which his ownership of land appears as the most
advantageous condition for the prosperity of his mode of production.
“Just as the
capitalist mode of production in general is based on the expropriation of the
conditions of labour from the labourers, so does it in agriculture presuppose
the expropriation of the rural labourers from the land and their subordination
to a capitalist, who carries on agriculture for the sake of profit…
“For our purposes it
is necessary to study the modern form of landed property, because our task is
to consider the specific conditions of production and circulation which arise
from the investment of capital in agriculture. Without this, our analysis of
capital would not be complete… (Or,
instead of agriculture, we can use mining because the laws are the same for
both.)
“Landed property is
based on the monopoly by certain persons over definite portions of the globe,
as exclusive spheres of their private will to the exclusion of all others. With
this in mind, the problem is to ascertain the economic value, that is, the realisation
of this monopoly on the basis of capitalist production.
“With the legal power
of these persons to use or misuse certain portions of the globe, nothing is
decided. The use of this power depends wholly upon economic conditions, which
are independent of their will. The legal view itself only means that the
landowner can do with the land what every owner of commodities can do with his
commodities. And this view, this legal view of free private ownership of land,
arises in the ancient world only with the dissolution of the organic order of
society, and in the modern world only with the development of capitalist
production…
“In the section (in Volume 1) dealing with primitive
accumulation we saw that this mode of production presupposes, on the one hand,
the separation of the direct producers from their position as mere accessories
to the land (in the form of vassals, serfs, slaves, etc.), and, on the other
hand, the expropriation of the mass of the people from the land.
“To this extent the
monopoly of landed property is a historical premise, and continues to remain
the basis of the capitalist mode of production, just as in all previous modes
of production which are based on the exploitation of the masses in one form or
another. But the form of landed property with which the incipient capitalist
mode of production is confronted does not suit it. It first creates for itself
the form required by subordinating agriculture to capital. It thus transforms
feudal landed property, clan property, small peasant property in mark communes
— no matter how divergent their juristic forms may be — into the economic form
corresponding to the requirements of this mode of production.
“One of the major
results of the capitalist mode of production is that, on the one hand, it transforms
agriculture from a mere empirical and mechanical self-perpetuating process
employed by the least developed part of society into the conscious scientific
application of agronomy, in so far as this is at all feasible under conditions
of private property; that it divorces landed property from the relations of
dominion and servitude, on the one hand, and, on the other, totally separates
land as an instrument of production from landed property and landowner — for
whom the land merely represents a certain money assessment which he collects by
virtue of his monopoly from the industrial capitalist, the capitalist farmer;
it dissolves the connection between landownership and the land so thoroughly
that the landowner may spend his whole life in Constantinople, while his
estates lie in Scotland. Landed property thus receives its purely economic form
by discarding all its former political and social embellishments and
associations, in brief all [its] traditional accessories…
“The rationalising of
agriculture, on the one hand, which makes it for the first time capable of
operating on a social scale, and the reduction ad absurdum of property in land,
on the other, are the great achievements of the capitalist mode of production.
Like all of its other historical advances, it also attained these by first completely impoverishing the
direct producers.”
Once again, Marx refers back to matters dealt with in Volume
1.
Among other things, Marx is here providing us with
explanations as to why the land question in South Africa is so intractable.
Land is part of capitalism, and so are mines. There can be no going back, but
only forward, because in its productive aspect land has never been more
socialised. Only in its ownership can land become more socialised, and it can only
be fully re-socialised by the complete abolition of capitalism.
As with banking, so also with landowning: Under capitalism
the take is a portion of surplus-value. This part shows how such rent arises
and how it is calculated for the various conditions, of which the first example
given is as clear as any, and can serve as typical.
- The above is to introduce the original reading-text: Capital Volume 3,
Chapter 38, Differential Rent: General Remarks.
- To download any of the CU courses in PDF files please click here.
0 comments:
Post a Comment
Post a Comment