Interest-Bearing Capital
Capital Volume 3, Part 5,
Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise. Interest-Bearing
Capital.
This is a long part of Volume 3 and is really too much with
its sixteen chapters (21 – 36), almost a book in itself, to be covered in a
single discussion. Therefore let us concentrate as before on the question of
whether Volume 1 of Capital is undermined or over-ruled by Volume 3.
Marx makes it clear that this is not the case at the
beginning of Chapter 23 where he writes:
“Interest, as we have
seen in the two preceding chapters, appears originally, is originally, and
remains in fact merely a portion of the
profit, i.e., of the surplus-value,
which the functioning capitalist, industrialist or merchant has to pay to the
owner and lender of money-capital whenever he uses loaned capital instead of
his own.”
These pages contain great good sense and a lot of assistance
to people trying to understand the “Global Economic Meltdown” that has been
going on since 2008, and is now also generally referred to as “the debt crisis”,
or just “the crisis”. As an example, here are some paragraphs from our sample Chapter
29, Component Parts of Bank Capital, (download linked below).
“We shall now consider
labour-power in contrast to the capital of the national debt, where a negative
quantity appears as capital — just as interest-bearing capital, in general, is
the fountainhead of all manner of insane
forms, so that debts, for instance, can appear to the banker as
commodities. Wages are conceived here as interest, and therefore labour-power
as the capital yielding this interest. For example, if the wage for one year
amounts to £50 and the rate of interest is 5%, the annual labour-power is equal
to a capital of £1,000. The insanity
of the capitalist mode of conception reaches its climax here, for instead of
explaining the expansion of capital on the basis of the exploitation of
labour-power, the matter is reversed and the productivity of labour power is
explained by attributing this mystical quality of interest-bearing capital to
labour-power itself. In the second half of the 17th century, this used to be a
favourite conception (for example, of Petty), but it is used even nowadays in
all seriousness by some vulgar economists and more particularly by some German
statisticians.[1] Unfortunately two disagreeably frustrating facts mar this
thoughtless conception. In the first place, the labourer must work in order to
obtain this interest. In the second place, he cannot transform the
capital-value of his labour-power into cash by transferring it. Rather, the
annual value of his labour-power is equal to his average annual wage, and what
he has to give the buyer in return through his labour is this same value plus a
surplus-value, i.e., the increment added by his labour. In a slave society, the
labourer has a capital-value, namely, his purchase price. And when he is hired
out, the hirer must pay, in the first place, the interest on this purchase
price, and, in addition, replace the annual wear and tear on the capital.
“The formation of a
fictitious capital is called capitalisation. Every periodic income is
capitalised by calculating it on the basis of the average rate of interest, as
an income which would be realised by a capital loaned at this rate of interest.
For example, if the annual income is £100 and the rate of interest 5%, then the
£100 would represent the annual interest on £2,000, and the £2,000 is regarded
as the capital-value of the legal title of ownership on the £100 annually. For
the person who buys this title of ownership, the annual income of £100
represents indeed the interest on his capital invested at 5%. All connection
with the actual expansion process of capital is thus completely lost, and the conception of capital as something with
automatic self-expansion properties is thereby strengthened.
“Even when the
promissory note — the security — does not represent a purely fictitious capital, as it does in the case of state debts,
the capital-value of such paper is
nevertheless wholly illusory. We
have previously seen in what manner the credit system creates associated
capital. The paper serves as title of ownership which represents this capital.
The stocks of railways, mines, navigation companies, and the like, represent
actual capital, namely, the capital invested and functioning in such
enterprises, or the amount of money advanced by the stockholders for the
purpose of being used as capital in such enterprises. This does not preclude
the possibility that these may represent pure swindle. But this capital does
not exist twice, once as the capital-value of titles of ownership (stocks) on
the one hand and on the other hand as the actual capital invested, or to be
invested, in those enterprises. It exists only in the latter form, and a share
of stock is merely a title of ownership to a corresponding portion of the
surplus-value to be realised by it. A may sell this title to B, and B may sell
it to C. These transactions do not alter anything in the nature of the problem.
A or B then has his title in the form of capital, but C has transformed his
capital into a mere title of ownership to the anticipated surplus-value from
the stock capital.”
It remains the case that in Volume 3, Karl Marx is
constantly referring back to Volume 1, and reminding us that whatever
“financial” profits (as we would now call them) there may be, these are only
portions of the surplus value generated at the point of production by the
capitalistic exploitation of living human labour-power.
Picture: Max
Keiser, of Russia Today’s “Keiser Report” television programme, in a London
taxi. Keiser is particularly eloquent about the insane role of “fictitious
capital” in present conditions, which appear not to have changed at all from
the time of Karl Marx, where finance capital is concerned. RT is on DSTV
channel 405.
- The above is to introduce the original reading-text: Capital Volume 3, Chapter 29, Component Parts of Bank
Capital.
- To download any of the CU courses in PDF files please click here.
0 comments:
Post a Comment
Post a Comment